CLICK THE LINK BELOW AND FILL FORM & ENJOY

Friday, January 16, 2009

M A R K E T

Market

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Jump to: navigation, search

A market outside of the walls of Tangier, by Louis Comfort Tiffany.

Markets may be any of a variety of different systems, institutions, procedures, social relations and infrastructures whereby persons trade, and goods and services are exchanged, forming part of the economy. Markets vary in size, range, geographic scale, location, types and variety of human communities, as well as the types of goods and services traded. Some examples include local farmers’ markets held in town squares or parking lots, shopping centers and shopping malls, international currency and commodity markets, legally created markets such as for pollution permits, and illegal markets such as the market for illicit drugs.

In mainstream economics, the concept of a market is any structure that allows buyers and sellers to exchange any type of goods, services and information. The exchange of goods or services for money is a transaction. Market participants consist of all the buyers and sellers of a good who influences its price. This influence is a major study of economics and has given rise to several theories and models concerning the basic market forces of supply and demand. There are two roles in markets, buyers and sellers. The market facilitates trade and enables the distribution and allocation of resources in a society. Markets allow any tradable item to be evaluated and priced. A market emerges more or less spontaneously or is constructed deliberately by human interaction in order to enable the exchange of rights (cf. ownership) of services and goods.
The historical origin of markets is the physical marketplaces which would often develop into small communities, towns and cities[citation needed].

Contents

[hide]

Types of markets

Types of markets

Although many markets exist in the traditional sense—such as a marketplace—there are various other types of markets and various organizational structures to assist their functions.

[edit] Financial markets

Financial markets facilitate the exchange of liquid assets. Most investors prefer investing in two markets, the stock markets and the bond markets. NYSE, AMEX, and the NASDAQ are the most common stock markets in the US. Futures markets, where contracts future delivery of goods are exchanged, these are often and outgrowth of general commodity markets.

Currency markets are used to trade one currency for another, and are often used for speculation on currency exchange rates.

The money market is the name for the global market for lending and borrowing.

[edit] Prediction markets

Prediction markets are a type of speculative market in which the goods exchanged are futures on the occurrence of certain events. They apply the market dynamics to facilitate information aggregation.

Organization of markets

Organization of markets

A market can be organized as an auction, as a private electronic market, as a shopping center, as a complex institution such as a stock market, and as an informal discussion between two individuals.

Markets of varying types can spontaneously arise whenever a party has interest in a good or service that some other party can provide. Hence there can be a market for cigarettes in correctional facilities, another for chewing gum in a playground, and yet another for contracts for the future delivery of a commodity. There can be black markets, where a good is exchanged illegally and virtual markets, such as eBay, in which buyers and sellers do not physically interact during negotiation. There can also be markets for goods under a command economy despite pressure to repress them.

Mechanisms of markets

Mechanisms of markets

In economics, a market that runs under laissez-faire policies is a free market. It is "free" in the sense that the government makes no attempt to intervene through taxes, subsidies, minimum wages, price ceilings, etc. Market prices may be distorted by a seller or sellers with monopoly power, or a buyer with monopsony power. Such price distortions can have an adverse effect on market participant's welfare and reduce the efficiency of market outcomes. Also, the level of organization or negotiation power of buyers, markedly affects the functioning of the market. Markets where price negotiations do not arrive at efficient outcomes for both sides are said to experience market failure.

STUDY OF "MARKETS"

Study of markets

The study of actual existing markets made up of persons interacting in space and place in diverse ways is widely seen as an antidote to abstract and all-encompassing concepts of “the market” and has historical precendent in the works of Ferdinand Braudel and Karl Polanyi. The latter term is now generally used in two ways. First, to denote the abstract mechanisms whereby supply and demand confront each other and deals are made. In its place, reference to markets reflects ordinary experience and the places, processes and institutions in which exchanges occurs.[1] Second, the market is often used to signify an integrated, all-encompassing and cohesive capitalist world economy. A widespread trend in economic history and sociology is skeptical of the idea that it is possible to develop a theory to capture an essence or unifying thread to markets. [2]. For economic geographers, reference to regional, local, or commodity specific markets can serve to undermine assumptions of global integration, and highlight geographic variations in the structures, institutions, histories, path dependencies, forms of interaction and modes of self-understanding of agents in different spheres of market exchange [3] Reference to actual markets can show capitalism not as a totalizing force or completely encompassing mode of economic activity, but rather as “a set of economic practices scattered over a landscape, rather than a systemic concentration of power” [4]

C. B. Macpherson identifies an underlying model of the market underlying Anglo-American liberal-democratic political economy and philosophy in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries: Persons are cast as self-interested individuals, who enter into contractual relations with other such individuals, concerning the exchange of goods or personal capacities cast as commodities, with the motive of maximizing pecuniary interest. The state and its governance systems are cast as outside of this framework.[5]). This model came to dominant economic thinking in the later nineteenth century, as economists such as Ricardo, Mill, Jevons, Walras and later neo-classical economics shifted from reference to geographically located marketplaces to an abstract “market” [6]. This tradition is continued in contemporary neoliberalism, where the market is held up as optimal for wealth creation and human freedom, and the states’ role imagined as minimal, reduced to that of upholding and keeping stable property rights, contract, and money supply. This allowed for boilerplate economic and institutional restructuring under structural adjustment and post-Communist reconstruction. [7]

Similar formalism occurs in a wide variety of social democratic and Marxist discourses that situate political action as antagonistic to the market. In particular, commodification theorists such as Georg Lukacs insist that market relations necessarily lead to undue exploitation of labour and so need to be opposed in toto. ,[8]). Pierre Bourdieu has suggested the market model is becoming self-realizing, in virtue of its wide acceptance in national and international institutions through the 1990s. [9]). The formalist conception faces a number of insuperable difficulties, concerning the putatively global scope of the market to cover the entire Earth, in terms of penetration of particular economies, and in terms of whether particular claims about the subjects (individuals with pecuniary interest), objects (commodities), and modes of exchange (transactions) apply to any actually existing markets.

A central theme of empirical analyses is the variation and proliferation of types of markets since the rise of capitalism and global scale economies. The Regulation School stresses the ways in which developed capitalist countries have implemented varying degrees and types of environmental, economic, and social regulation, taxation and public spending, fiscal policy and government provisioning of goods, all of which have transformed markets in uneven and geographical varied ways and created a variety of mixed economies. Drawing on concepts of institutional variance and path dependency, varieties of capitalism theorists (such as Hall and Soskice) identify two dominant modes of economic ordering in the developed capitalist countries, “coordinated market economies” such as Germany and Japan, and an Anglo-American “liberal market economies”. However, such approaches imply that the Anglo-American liberal market economies in fact operate in a matter close to the abstract notion of “the market”. While Anglo-American countries have seen increasing introduction of neo-liberal forms of economic ordering, this has not lead to simple convergence, but rather a variety of hybrid institutional orderings. [10]. Rather, a variety of new markets have emerged, such as for carbon trading or rights to pollute. In some cases, such as emerging markets for water, different forms of privatization of different aspects of previously state run infrastructure have created hybrid private-public formations and graded degrees of commodification, commercialization and privatization [11]

Problematic for market formalism is the relationship between formal capitalist economic processes and a variety of alternative forms, ranging from semi-feudal and peasant economies widely operative in many developing economies, to informal markets, barter systems, worker cooperatives, or illegal trades that occur in most developed countries. Practices of incorporation of non-Western peoples into global markets in the nineteenth and twentieth century did not merely result in the quashing of former social economic institutions. Rather, various modes of articulation arose between transformed and hybridized local traditions and social practices and the emergence world economy. So called capitalist markets in fact include and depend on a wide range of geographically situated economic practices that do not follow the market model. Economies are thus hybrids of market and non-market elements[12]

Helpful here is J. K. Gibson-Graham’s complex topology of the diversity of contemporary market economies describing different types of transactions, labour, and economic agents. Transactions can occur in underground markets (such as for marijuana) or be artificially protected (such as for patents). They can cover the sale of public goods under privatization schemes to co-operative exchanges and occur under varying degrees of monopoly power and state regulation. Likewise, there are a wide variety of economic agents, which engage in different types of transactions on different terms: One cannot assume the practices of a religious kindergarten, multinational corporation, state enterprise, or community-based cooperative can be subsumed under the same logic of calculability (pp. 53-78). This emphasis on proliferation can also be contrasted with continuing scholarly attempts to show underlying cohesive and structural similarities to different markets. [13]

A prominent entry point for challenging the market model’s applicability concerns exchange transactions and the homo economicus assumption of self-interest maximization. There are now a number of streams of economic sociological analysis of markets focusing on the role of the social in transactions, and the ways transactions involve social networks and relations of trust, cooperation and other bonds. [13]. Economic geographers in turn draw attention to the ways in exchange transactions occur against the backdrop of institutional, social and geographic processes, including class relations, uneven development, and historically contingent path dependencies [14]. A useful schema is provided by Michel Callon’s concept of framing: Each economic act or transaction occurs against, incorporates and also re-performs a geographically and cultural specific complex of social histories, institutional arrangements, rules and connections. These network relations are simultaneously bracketed, so that persons and transactions may be disentangled from thick social bonds. The character of calculability is imposed upon agents as they come to work in markets and are “formatted” as calculative agencies. Market exchanges contain a history of struggle and contestation that produced actors predisposed to exchange under certain sets of rules. As such market transactions can never be disembedded from social and geographic relations and there is no sense to talking of degrees of embeddedness and disembeddeness [15].

An emerging theme worthy of further study is the interrelationship, interpenetrability and variations of concepts of persons, commodities, and modes of exchange under particular market formations. This is most pronounced in recent movement towards post-structuralist theorizing that draws on Foucault and Actor Network Theory and stress relational aspects of personhood, and dependence and integration into networks and practical systems. Commodity network approaches further both deconstruct and show alternatives to the market models concept of commodities. Here, both researchers and market actors are understood as reframing commodities in terms of processes and social and ecological relationships. Rather than a mere objectification of things traded, the complex network relationships of exchange in different markets calls on agents to alternatively deconstruct or “get with” the fetish of commodities. [16] Gibson-Graham thus read a variety of alternative markets, for fair trade and organic foods, or those using Local Exchange Trading Systems as not only contributing to proliferation, but also forging new modes of ethical exchange and economic subjectivities.

Most markets are regulated by state wide laws and regulations. While barter markets exist, most markets use currency or some other form of money.

NOTES ON "MARKET"

Notes

  1. ^ Callon, M. (1998) "Introduction: The Embeddedness of Economic Markets in Economics." In The Laws of the Markets, edited by Michel Callon. Basic Blackwell/The Sociological Review pp 1-57 1998, p.2).
  2. ^ Swedberg, Richard (1994) “Markets as Social Structures” The Handbook of Economic Sociology. Ed. Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg. Princeton University Press. 255-2821994, p. 258)
  3. ^ Peck, J. (2005) “Economic Geographies in Space” Economic Geography 81(2) 129-175.
  4. ^ (Gibson-Graham, J.K. (2006) Postcapitalist Politics. University of Minnesota Press,. p.2).
  5. ^ (MacPherson, C.B. (1962) The Political Theory of Possessive Individualism: From Hobbes to Locke. Oxford Clarendon Press. p.3
  6. ^ (Swedberg, 1994, p. 258
  7. ^ Harvey, David (2005) A Short History of Neoliberalism Oxford University Press.
  8. ^ Lukács, Georg. (1971) History and Class Consciousness. Trans. Rodney Livingstone. Merlin Press. London.p. 87
  9. ^ Bourdieu, Pierre (1999) Acts of Resistance: Against the Tyranny of the Market. The New Press.p. 95
  10. ^ Peck, supra, p. 154)
  11. ^ Bakker, Karen (2005) “Neoliberalizing Nature?: Market Environmentalism in water supply in England and Wales” Annals of the Association of American Geographers 95 (3), 542-565
  12. ^ (Mitchell, Timothy (2002) Rule of Experts. University of California Pressp. 270; Gibson-Graham 2006, supra pp. 53-78)
  13. ^ a b Swedberg, 1994, p. 267
  14. ^ Martin, Ron (2000) “Institutional Approaches in Economic Geography” Handbook of Economic Geography. Ed. Eric Sheppard and Trevor J. Barnes. Blackwell Publishers.Peck, 2005
  15. ^ Callon, 1998; Mitchell, 2002, p. 291,
  16. ^ Hughes, Alex (2005) “Geographies of Exchange and Circulation: alternative trading spaces” Progress in Human Geography

TRADE

Trade

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Jump to: navigation, search

This article is about the economical mechanism. For other uses, see Trade (disambiguation).

Trade is the willing exchange of goods, services, or both. Trade is also called commerce. A mechanism that allows trade is called a market. The original form of trade was barter, the direct exchange of goods and services. Modern traders instead generally negotiate through a medium of exchange, such as money. As a result, buying can be separated from selling, or earning. The invention of money (and later credit, paper money and non-physical money) greatly simplified and promoted trade. Trade between two traders is called bilateral trade, while trade between more than two traders is called multilateral trade.

Trade exists for many reasons. Due to specialization and division of labor, most people concentrate on a small aspect of production, trading for other products. Trade exists between regions because different regions have a comparative advantage in the production of some tradable commodity, or because different regions' size allows for the benefits of mass production. As such, trade at market prices between locations benefits both locations.

Trading can also refer to the action performed by traders and other market agents in the financial markets.

Contents

[hide]

HISTORY OF TRADE

History of trade

Part of a series on Trade routes

Amber Road · Hærvejen . Incense Route

Kamboja-Dvaravati Route . King's Highway

Roman-India routes . Royal Road

Silk Road · Spice Route . Tea route

Varangians to the Greeks · Via Maris

Triangular trade .Volga trade route

Trans-Saharan trade . Salt Route

Hanseatic League . Grand Trunk Road

Trade originated with the start of communication in prehistoric times. Trading was the main facility of prehistoric people, who bartered goods and services from each other before the innovation of the modern day currency. Peter Watson dates the history of long-distance commerce from circa 150,000 years ago.[1]

Trade is believed to have taken place throughout much of recorded human history. There is evidence of the exchange of obsidian and flint during the stone age. Materials used for creating jewelry were traded with Egypt since 3000 BC. Long-range trade routes first appeared in the 3rd millennium BC, when Sumerians in Mesopotamia traded with the Harappan civilization of the Indus Valley. The Phoenicians were noted sea traders, traveling across the Mediterranean Sea, and as far north as Britain for sources of tin to manufacture bronze. For this purpose they established trade colonies the Greeks called emporia. From the beginning of Greek civilization until the fall of the Roman empire in the 5th century, a financially lucrative trade brought valuable spice to Europe from the far east, including China. Roman commerce allowed its empire to flourish and endure. The Roman empire produced a stable and secure transportation network that enabled the shipment of trade goods without fear of significant piracy.

The fall of the Roman empire, and the succeeding Dark Ages brought instability to Western Europe and a near collapse of the trade network. Nevertheless some trade did occur. For instance, Radhanites were a medieval guild or group (the precise meaning of the word is lost to history) of Jewish merchants who traded between the Christians in Europe and the Muslims of the Near East.

The Sogdians dominated the East-West trade route known as the Silk Road after the 4th century AD up to the 8th century AD, with Suyab and Talas ranking among their main centeres in the north. They were the main caravan merchants of Central Asia.

From the 8th to the 11th century, the Vikings and Varangians traded as they sailed from and to Scandinavia. Vikings sailed to Western Europe, while Varangians to Russia. The Hanseatic League was an alliance of trading cities that maintained a trade monopoly over most of Northern Europe and the Baltic, between the 13th and 17th centuries.

Vasco da Gama restarted the European Spice trade in 1498. Prior to his sailing around Africa, the flow of spice into Europe was controlled by Islamic powers, especially Egypt. The spice trade was of major economic importance and helped spur the Age of Exploration. Spices brought to Europe from distant lands were some of the most valuable commodities for their weight, sometimes rivaling gold.

In the 16th century, Holland was the centre of free trade, imposing no exchange controls, and advocating the free movement of goods. Trade in the East Indies was dominated by Portugal in the 16th century, the Netherlands in the 17th century, and the British in the 18th century. The Spanish Empire developed regular trade links across both the Atlantic and the Pacific Oceans.

In 1776, Adam Smith published the paper An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. It criticised Mercantilism, and argued that economic specialisation could benefit nations just as much as firms. Since the division of labour was restricted by the size of the market, he said that countries having access to larger markets would be able to divide labour more efficiently and thereby become more productive. Smith said that he considered all rationalisations of import and export controls "dupery", which hurt the trading nation at the expense of specific industries.

In 1799, the Dutch East India Company, formerly the world's largest company, became bankrupt, partly due to the rise of competitive free trade.

In 1817, David Ricardo, James Mill and Robert Torrens showed that free trade would benefit the industrially weak as well as the strong, in the famous theory of comparative advantage. In Principles of Political Economy and Taxation Ricardo advanced the doctrine still considered the most counterintuitive in economics:

When an inefficient producer sends the merchandise it produces best to a country able to produce it more efficiently, both countries benefit.

The ascendancy of free trade was primarily based on national advantage in the mid 19th century. That is, the calculation made was whether it was in any particular country's self-interest to open its borders to imports.

John Stuart Mill proved that a country with monopoly pricing power on the international market could manipulate the terms of trade through maintaining tariffs, and that the response to this might be reciprocity in trade policy. Ricardo and others had suggested this earlier. This was taken as evidence against the universal doctrine of free trade, as it was believed that more of the economic surplus of trade would accrue to a country following reciprocal, rather than completely free, trade policies. This was followed within a few years by the infant industry scenario developed by Mill promoting the theory that government had the "duty" to protect young industries, although only for a time necessary for them to develop full capacity. This became the policy in many countries attempting to industrialise and out-compete English exporters. Milton Friedman later continued this vein of thought, showing that in a few circumstances tariffs might be beneficial to the host country; but never for the world at large.[2]

The Great Depression was a major economic recession that ran from 1929 to the late 1930s. During this period, there was a great drop in trade and other economic indicators.

The lack of free trade was considered by many as a principal cause of the depression. Only during the World War II the recession ended in United States. Also during the war, in 1944, 44 countries signed the Bretton Woods Agreement, intended to prevent national trade barriers, to avoid depressions. It set up rules and institutions to regulate the international political economy: the International Monetary Fund and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (later divided into the World Bank and Bank for International Settlements). These organisations became operational in 1946 after enough countries ratified the agreement. In 1947, 23 countries agreed to the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade to promote free trade.

Free trade advanced further in the late 20th century and early 2000s:

Development of Money

Development of money

Main article: History of money

The first instances of money were objects with intrinsic value. This is called commodity money and includes any commonly-available commodity that has intrinsic value; historical examples include pigs, rare seashells, whale's teeth, and (often) cattle. In medieval Iraq, bread was used as an early form of money. In Mexico under Montezuma cocoa beans were money. [1]

Roman denarius

Currency was introduced as a standardised money to facilitate a wider exchange of goods and services. This first stage of currency, where metals were used to represent stored value, and symbols to represent commodities, formed the basis of trade in the Fertile Crescent for over 1500 years.

Numismatists have examples of coins from the earliest large-scale societies, although these were initially unmarked lumps of precious metal.[3]

Ancient Sparta minted coins from iron to discourage its citizens from engaging in foreign trade.

The system of commodity money in many instances evolved into a system of representative money. In this system, the material that constitutes the money itself had very little intrinsic value, but nonetheless such money achieves significant market value through scarcity or controlled supply.

Current trends

Current trends

[edit] Doha rounds

Main article: Doha round

The Doha round of World Trade Organization negotiations aims to lower barriers to trade around the world, with a focus on making trade fairer for developing countries. Talks have been hung over a divide between the rich, developed countries, and the major developing countries (represented by the G20). Agricultural subsidies are the most significant issue upon which agreement has been hardest to negotiate. By contrast, there was much agreement on trade facilitation and capacity building.

The Doha round began in Doha, Qatar, and negotiations have subsequently continued in: Cancún, Mexico; Geneva, Switzerland; and Paris, France and Hong Kong.

[edit] China

Beginning around 1978, the government of the People's Republic of China (PRC) began an experiment in economic reform. Previously the Communist nation had employed the Soviet-style centrally planned economy, with limited results. They would now utilise a more market-oriented economy, particularly in the so-called Special Economic Zones located in the Guangdong, Fujian, and Hainan.

This reform has been spectacularly successful. By 2004, the GDP of the nation has quadrupled since 2008 and foreign trade exceeded USD 1 trillion. As of 2005, China had become the 3rd largest exporter behind Germany and the United States. This occurred in spite of the backlash from the shootings following Tiananmen Square protests of 1989. In 2007, China's two-way trade totaled US$2,173.8 billion, and was $262.2 billion in surplus. Foreign exchange reserves, the largest in the world, topped $1.8 trillion in mid-2008.

In 1991 the PRC joined the Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation group, a trade-promotion forum. More recently, in 2001 they also joined the World Trade Organization. See also: Economy of the People's Republic of China

International Trade

International trade

Main article: International trade

International Trade Series

v d e

International trade

History of international trade

Political views

Fair trade

Trade justice

Free trade

Protectionism


Economic integration

Preferential trading area

Free trade area

Customs union

Common market

Economic and monetary union

Other

Trade pact

Trade bloc

Trade creation

Trade diversion

International trade is the exchange of goods and services across national borders. In most countries, it represents a significant part of GDP. While international trade has been present throughout much of history (see Silk Road, Amber Road), its economic, social, and political importance have increased in recent centuries, mainly because of Industrialisation, advanced transportation, globalisation, multinational corporations, and outsourcing. In fact, it is probably the increasing prevalence of international trade that is usually meant by the term "globalisation".

Empirical evidence for the success of trade can be seen in the contrast between countries such as South Korea, which adopted a policy of export-oriented industrialisation, and India, which historically had a more closed policy (although it has begun to open its economy, as of 2005). South Korea has done much better by economic criteria than India over the past fifty years, though its success also has to do with effective state institutions.

Trade sanctions against a specific country are sometimes imposed, in order to punish that country for some action. An embargo, a severe form of externally imposed isolation, is a blockade of all trade by one country on another. For example, the United States has had an embargo against Cuba for over 40 years.

Although there are usually few trade restrictions within countries, international trade is usually regulated by governmental quotas and restrictions, and often taxed by tariffs. Tariffs are usually on imports, but sometimes countries may impose export tariffs or subsidies. All of these are called trade barriers. If a government removes all trade barriers, a condition of free trade exists. A government that implements a protectionist policy establishes trade barriers.

The fair trade movement, also known as the trade justice movement, promotes the use of labour, environmental and social standards for the production of commodities, particularly those exported from the Third and Second Worlds to the First World. Such ideas have also sparked a debate on whether trade itself should be codified as a human right.[4]

Standards may be voluntarily adhered to by importing firms, or enforced by governments through a combination of employment and commercial law. Proposed and practiced fair trade policies vary widely, ranging from the commonly adhered to prohibition of goods made using slave labour to minimum price support schemes such as those for coffee in the 1980s. Non-governmental organizations also play a role in promoting fair trade standards by serving as independent monitors of compliance with fairtrade labelling requirements.

Organization of trade

Organization of trade

Patterns of organizing and administering trade include:

[edit] International organizations

[edit] Free trade areas

Sunday, January 11, 2009

Top News of the Day

[[News No 1.]]As part of its probe on scam-tainted Satyam, RBI today collected particulars of transactions that various banks including The bank, in a statement, had said that it did not have any fund-based exposure to Satyam Computer Services other than a marginal exposure of about Rs 3-crore on account of a forward contract.
Satyam is also maintaining a deposit with ICICI Bank in a current account. The balance in this account is not material, ICICI bank said. We have submitted the details of our business deals with Satyam to the Reserve bank. In the wake of these developments (in Satyam), banks are bound to be extra cautious while lending to such corporates, SBIs Chief Financial Officer Ashok Mukand told.When asked, Citibank declined to comment if the company was its client and whether the bank had given details to RBI.
We are unable to comment due to client confidentiality, a spokesperson of the bank said.
SBI is undertood to have extended loans to the Hyderabad-based company, but the officials declined to divulge the details of its exposure to Satyam.
Leading public-sector lender, Bank of Baroda, has also submitted the details of its insignificant exposure to Satyam to the apex bank, its CMD, M D Mallya said.
We do not have any fund-based exposure to this company (Satyam), Mallya said. However, the lender has some current account deposits of Satyam.
Leading private-sector lender, ICICI Bank, is also believed to have provided the details to the RBI about its dealings with Satyam. [[News No 2.]]CARE has assigned ‘CARE A+’ rating to the proposed Rs 100 crore non convertible debentures issue of Bharati Shipyard Ltd, which is to say the NCDs offer adequate safety for timely servicing and carry low credit risk.
Further, CARE has reaffirmed the ‘CARE A+’ rating assigned to the long-term bank facilities of Bharati Shipyard. Also, CARE has reaffirmed the ‘PR1+’ rating to its short-term bank facilities. The short-term and long-term bank facilities aggregate Rs.3,031 crore, revised from Rs.3,116 crore.
The ratings derive strength from professionally qualified and experienced promoters as well as management, in-house vessel design capabilities of Bharati Shipyard, comfortable gearing level, stable profitability margins, strong order-book position demonstrating visibility in revenue and higher proportion of repeat orders in the order book.
However, the rating is constrained by project risk associated with the expansion projects, high working-capital requirement in the wake of increasing order book and competition from global players in the event of slowdown in the ship building activity.
The inherent cyclicality in the ship building sector, execution of huge order book within the timeframe in view of the possible delay in receipt of equipment for shipbuilding and the government decisions regarding continuation of subsidies are the key rating sensitivities.
Bharati Shipyard is engaged in design and construction of various types of sea-going vessels. Over the years, it has upgraded from manufacturing inland cargo barges and deep-sea trawlers to build tugs, sophisticated offshore support vessels and drilling rigs. BSL has its facilities located at Dabhol (Maharashtra), Ghodbunder (Thane), Ratnagiri (an EOU), Goa (an EOU) and Kolkatta.
The Dabhol and Mangalore yards are under implementation. Since 1987, the company built and delivered over 50 vessels, with 39 vessels being delivered in last nine years.
As on August 31, 2008, Bharati Shipyard had an order-book position of 54 vessels under construction, valued approximately at Rs.5,023 crore, to be executed over the next four years. The export orders constitute 70% of the total order size. [[News No 3.]]Bharat Forge, the countrys largest forgings company, has reviewed its earlier decision to issue non convertible debentures due to bad equity markets.
The Rs 400-crore debenture issue, with detachable warrants, was scheduled to be issued on a rights basis and would have funded Bharat Forges growth plans.
The decision to review the issue was taken at a board meeting on Friday, Bharat Forge said in a statement to the BSE.
Shares of Bharat Forge were up 0.3% to Rs 91.50 on the BSE in intra day trading.
Last month, the auto component maker had approved a proposal to raise Rs 250 crore through issue of debentures on a private placement basis to Life Insurance Corporation of India. [[News No 4.]]The board meeting of Rolta India will be held on 19 January 2009 to take record on the unaudited financial results for the quarter ended 31 December 2008 (Q2) of the financial year 2008-009. [[News No 5.]]KLG Systel has announced that the Power System Solution (PSS) division of the company has been awarded repeat order aggregating Rs 30.60 crore from Uttar Haryana Bijli Vitran Nigam (UHBVN) for EPC project.The company made this announcement during the trading hours today, 10 January 2009.#### Vijaya Bank has announced a reduction in its Benchmark Prime Lending Rate (BPLR) from 13.25 per cent to 12.75 per cent with effect from January 12, 2009.
While deciding on the BPLR, the Banks Asset Liability Management Committee also reviewed the interest rates offered on deposits of various maturities in the light of continued downward trends in benchmark rates, a release said.
Accordingly, interest rates on the Banks retail deposit schemes across various slabs have also been revised downwards in the range of 25 to 75 basis points.
"Our objective is to contribute progressively to a revival in the real economy. I expect the reduction in the BPLR to enable pick-up in credit, especially from the productive sectors as also the public at large," said Vijaya Bank CMD Albert Tauro in the release.

Do's & Dont's of stock market

What you Must NOT Do in Stock Market
Don't panic
Don't make huge investments
Don't chase performance
Don't ignore expenses
Don't panic
What You Must Do in Indian Stock Market
Don't panic
Get Rid of the Junk
Diversify
Belive in your Investment
Stick To your Strategy
For Explanation Click On More

latest news on stock market

Topic :- Closing Note
Market remained very volatile throughout the day and closed in red zone.For today also Satyam is to be blamed.Satyam traded on on the BSE Sensex and NSE Nifty for last time on Friday — it was announced that Satyam would be replaced by Sun Pharma and Reliance Capital respective on the two indices.Volumes were better in todays trade as well. Total traded turnover was at Rs 64,891.47 crore. This includes Rs 12,984.81 crore from NSE Cash segment Rs 47,709.01 crore from NSE F&O and the balance Rs 4,197.65 crore from BSE Cash segment.On Monday we may see weak opening followed by recovery in the market but global cues will play important role.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Topic :- Time:3.10 P.M
After to much volatility now market seems to be range bound.If nifty (spot) manage to trade above(resistance) 2898-2921 then some recovery may be seen.If Nifty trades below(support) 2843-2820 then good profit booking is expected.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Topic :- Time:2.05 P.M
Nifty(spot) if trade above (resistance) 2902-2935 some recovery is expected.If Nifty breaks below (support) 2840-2824 good profit booking is expected. Infra stocks moving now.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Topic :- Time:12.50 P.M
Top 5 Losser in NIFTY as on 9th January, 2009 at 12:45 Pm.
Satyam Computer Services Ltd(SATYAMCOMP) Down 45.59%
DLF Limited(DLF) Down 16.70%
Unitech Ltd(UNITECH) Down 12.65%
Siemens Ltd(SIEMENS) Down 11.10%
Reliance Communications Limited(RCOM) Down 10.07%.
www.ShareTipsInfo.com Team
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Topic :- Time:12.00 P.M
Market Out Look: NIFTY is Having Resistance at 2850-2860(Spot) Levels. If Nifty is able to Cross & Sustain above these level then we can see some recovery in market which can take Nifty to 2880-2910-2945 levels Very Soon.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Topic :- Time:11.46 A.M
For now Nifty spot above 2860 can see some recovery now and if Nifty spot breaks 2840 we can see some profit booking in the market.Inflation for weekend is 5.91% VS 6.61% last week. Whole story of Satyam biggest scam updated on our site. Please find same in articles section.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Topic :- Time:10.55 A.M
As mentioned market will see selling pressure.Now recovery is expected only above 2910. Below 2860 we can further see selling pressure in the market.We were asking our clients to stay away from SATYAM Counter. The company is tainted in all respects & there was possibility of Complete loss of Capital of Investors & traders. In Last 2 Trading Session this counter slips from 188 to Just 6.30 Rs. & Now Trading at 20 Rs.The Satyam Counter will be out from NIFTY & SENSEX from this Monday that is 12th January, 2009. In Nifty it will be replaced by RELCAPITAL & In SENSEX by SUNPHARMA.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Topic :- Opening Note
Negative opening expected.For morning session Nifty spot below 2900 to remain weak.More profit booking to come if Nifty breaks 2875 level. Recovery only expected if Nifty manages to trade above 2950.Sentiments in market are very bad.Trade in less quantity or avoid early trade.